Talk:Highest averages method

Page contents not supported in other languages.
From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

2003 comments[edit]

First, I can't tell you how happy that user:Ruhrjung added this page, and the sainte-lague one, and that we've had all these people working on these pages. I'm going to suggest that we replace the example with the following made-up one: apportioning seats to states for an 8-seat council of New England states. The reasons I'd want to make the change are: 1) the "preferences" (in this case, population) aren't made up, so nobody has to account for "is this a realistic spread of preferences or is this tailored", and 2) it emphasises the difference between d'H and S-L (that's why I chose not to use modified S-L).

However, I'm not going to be bold because Ruhrjung clearly put in a lot of work to make the existing example (whose table structure I have copied) and I don't want to offend him. Is this okay? Which example do you think is better?

d'Hondt method   Sainte-Laguë method
States MA CT ME NH RI VT MA CT ME NH RI VT
Pop. (1000s) 6,349 3,405 1,274 1,235 1,048 608 6,349 3,405 1,274 1,235 1,048 608
mandate quotient
     
1 6,349 3,405 1,274 1,235 1,048 608 6,349 3,405 1,274 1,235 1,048 608
2 3,175 1,703 637 2,116 1,135 425 412
3 2,116 1,135 1,270 681
4 1,587 907
5 1,270
seat seat allocation
1 6,349             6,349          
2 3,405          3,405         
3 3,175          2,116        
4 2,116             1,274      
5 1,703          1,270          
6 1,587               1,235    
7   1,274         1,135        
8 1,270                  1,048  

Also, whichever example we use, I want to use and explain a table like this:

d'Hondt

method

Sainte-Laguë method
States MA CT ME NH RI VT MA CT ME NH RI VT
Seats 5 2 1 0 0 0 3 2 1 1 1 0
Ratio 3.65 1.96 0.73 0.71 0.60 0.35 3.65 1.96 0.73 0.71 0.60 0.35
Diff. +1.35 +0.04 +0.27 -0.71 -0.60 -0.35 -0.65 +0.04 +0.27 +0.29 +0.40 -0.35
  • Seats=seats allocated under this system
  • Ratio=Total Seats to allocate*State Population/N.E. Population
  • Diff.= Seats-Ratio

-- User:DanKeshet

Go along. I'm busy at work for the next three days - probably without any time to "recover" in front of the computer.

Your proposed addition is quite in line with my thoughts on what's relevant and interesting. I had a thought with the made up number of votes, namely that they make percentage-comparisons easy for the untrained, as the total number of casted votes was set to 100.000. And as quite a few elections in the last 30 years (i.e. in my lifetime:-) has been done with these methods, it never occured to me that one of them ought to be taken as an example. By making up the numbers, the which-and-why question was avoided. :-) My idea was to add rows to the tables with approximately the following information:

const.                     result in percentage 
size         d'Hondt                              Sainte-Laguë
         party 1    party 2,   party 3...       party 1,  party 2,  party 3...
 1       100% (1)                               100% (1)
 2       100% (2)                               100% (2)
 3        67% (2)    33% (1)                     67% (2)   33% (1)
 4        50% (2)    25% (1)    25% (1)          50% (2)   25% (1)   25% (1)
 5
 6
 7
 8      
 9
10

I had further had the idea to have two sections in the article with two headings: One for comparing the unmodified Sainte-Laguë method, and one (as I had started) for the method with the first divisor set equal to 1.4 - and how unlikely it might now ever seem, I had actually finished that work when my computer locked, and the work was lost, ...and I soured.

Do as you like with the figures. I wouldn't advice you to use any New England example, as the whole wikipedia project already as it is is pretty much US-centered, which isn't always a good thing, and as it might seem odd to list half-a-dozen of non-US countries where the method is in uncontroversial use, and then give an example from USA. However, I'm glad someone more than me has found it relevant to work on these articles, and I'm sure the end result will become pretty good whatever you choose to do of your New England idea.

best regards!
-- Ruhrjung 17:52 28 Jul 2003 (UTC)


Uf! I'm sorry to hear about your computer lockup! I look forward to the text being regenerated. So, I agree about the US-centrism, and I'll drop the New England example, but I still think it's better to use a "real-life" made-up example (EU? AU?) than an out-of-the-blue made-up example.

By the way, do you know about Wikipedia:WikiProject Voting Systems? You don't need to know anything about the project in order to participate, but if we want project-wide standards, then that could be a place we work them out.

See you,

DanKeshet 04:35, 29 Jul 2003 (UTC)

One more step taken, on the outlined road, but the weather is nice, and the summer short up here in the North, why I refuse to hide indoors more. :))
-- Ruhrjung 09:05, 5 Aug 2003 (UTC)

No worries. Relax, take your time, it will still be here when you get back. I have added a section on the other way of conceiving of the highest averages methods. I understand that nobody who didn't already understand what I wrote will probably gain an understanding, but I meant it as starter text which can be ruthlessly rewritten until it actually explains the reasoning behind the procedures. DanKeshet 17:49, 6 Aug 2003 (UTC)

I saw that. The colour is nice. Your attempt to explain the method as if it was largest remainder method is maybe not quite simple to understand, that's true, but if so, it can surely be mended in due time. I'm for instance pretty fond of the following sparse wording, quoted from http://www.barnsdle.demon.co.uk/vote/appor.html:

That was the quota definition of Webster's method. Webster actually worded his own definition slightly differrently, in a way that's very brief: To determine each party's seats:
Divide each party's votes by the same number & round off.
This common divisor is chosen so that the total number of seats awarded equals the desired house (or district) size.
Again, this common divisor is a common ratio between seats & votes, and rounding off puts each party's seats as close as possible to what that common ratio calls for.
Some object that the divisor definition is unclear because it orders division by an as-yet unspecified number, unlike the quota definition. But Webster's divisor definition has the best brevity.

-- Ruhrjung 13:58, 7 Aug 2003 (UTC)

Would it be useful to mention minor methods like Hill's method? (Hill's method is used for assigning representatives to US states, and has the property that every "party" gets at least one representative.) Rob Speer 08:04, Jul 17, 2004 (UTC)

why?[edit]

Im having trouble understanding the exact rationale behind these methods. Why do seemingly provisionaly choosen divisors result in a proportional result? Also, why are such complicated ways of allocation used at all; it would seem that simply dividing the number of votes each party won with the total votes and multiplying this with the number of available seets, rounded down, and then largest remaining fractions up to the remaining number of seets chosen (if you write this out, it is mathematically equivalent to Hare quota) would by definition result in the most proportional results, and its the most intuitive - mathematically most evident - way of doing this. --195.29.116.30 04:54, 19 July 2006 (UTC)[reply]


____________

Let’s suppose those figures:

A: 340,000 B: 280,000 C: 160,000 D: 60,000 E: 15,000

The result using Sainte-Laguë method would be: 3, 2, 1, 1

If we use D'Hond method, then: 2, 2, 2, 1.

It seems to contradict the idea of a 'more proportional' system.

Thanks. —Preceding unsigned comment added by 81.35.196.9 (talk) 15:03, 13 November 2008 (UTC)[reply]


  • You may have made an error with your D'Hondt calculations: I make it 3,3,1,0 as 340000/3 > 280000/3 > 160000/2 > 60000/1. As for which is more proportional, I have my doubts about any system which does not guarantee that a party with more than half the votes will win at least half the seats. --Rumping (talk) 10:17, 5 June 2009 (UTC)[reply]

Modified S-L[edit]

The table calculates modified S-L with 1.4, 3.4, 5.4,.... This results in a top row with a divisor of 1.4, which is incomparable with all the other tables. Why not use the mathematically equivalent series 1, 2 3/7 (2.429..), 3 6/7,...? This would lead to more comparable numbers (although it would take a footnote to explain it.) 187.143.7.74 (talk) 14:49, 12 February 2010 (UTC)[reply]

No, it doesn't. Modified S-L (and the table) uses 1.4, 3, 5, .... --Roentgenium111 (talk) 18:05, 24 January 2013 (UTC)[reply]
The table has been modified to allow for direct comparisons across rows, by using 0.5, 1.5... for Sainte-Lague (which is the "more correct" fencepost sequence; using 1, 3, ... is just a convenience to avoid dealing with fractions). Closed Limelike Curves (talk) 21:02, 2 February 2024 (UTC)[reply]

Sainte-Laguë and splits[edit]

I have radically changed the part which previously said: "D'Hondt favors the merging of parties, while Sainte-Laguë favours neither merging nor splitting parties which expect to gain more than 1 or 2 seats. (It does favor splitting of very small parties – expecting to gain only 1-2 seats – into still smaller ones). Modified Saint-Laguë prevents this splitting advantage for small parties, while remaining impartial towards party size for all larger parties" on the grounds that it is not true. Just to illustrate from the current example, if the Yellow party split its 47,000 votes into 6 new parties with about 7,800 votes each, it would win 6 seats in both unmodified Sainte-Laguë and modified Sainte-Laguë (with unmodified Sainte-Laguë it might even successfully do a split into 7 parties with 6,700 votes each so going from 4 to 7 seats). The reality is that Sainte-Laguë often rewards splits, even for large parties, rather like the Hare quotas in Hong Kong. --Rumping (talk) 16:45, 22 May 2015 (UTC)[reply]

Fill gaps from the German Wikipedia[edit]

For missing references and other useful material (including mathematical properties of the apportionments achieved and other algorithms always yielding the same apportionment) see http://de.wikipedia.org/wiki/Sitzzuteilungsverfahren . -- Wegner8 07:13, 19 October 2017 (UTC) — Preceding unsigned comment added by Wegner8 (talkcontribs)

External links modified[edit]

Hello fellow Wikipedians,

I have just modified one external link on Highest averages method. Please take a moment to review my edit. If you have any questions, or need the bot to ignore the links, or the page altogether, please visit this simple FaQ for additional information. I made the following changes:

When you have finished reviewing my changes, you may follow the instructions on the template below to fix any issues with the URLs.

This message was posted before February 2018. After February 2018, "External links modified" talk page sections are no longer generated or monitored by InternetArchiveBot. No special action is required regarding these talk page notices, other than regular verification using the archive tool instructions below. Editors have permission to delete these "External links modified" talk page sections if they want to de-clutter talk pages, but see the RfC before doing mass systematic removals. This message is updated dynamically through the template {{source check}} (last update: 18 January 2022).

  • If you have discovered URLs which were erroneously considered dead by the bot, you can report them with this tool.
  • If you found an error with any archives or the URLs themselves, you can fix them with this tool.

Cheers.—InternetArchiveBot (Report bug) 18:52, 3 November 2017 (UTC)[reply]

is huntington-hill example correct[edit]

Hi

not sure on this but I'm not sure the huntington hill example is correct.

because the divisor is n(n+1) the first number in the series is infinity - hence all who meet the threshold get at least one seat. so the first round should both eliminate two of the parties, and assign four seats to the other parties leaving six to be allocated. these will go four to yellow, one to white, one to red, giving overall allocation of 5,2,2,1. In this example it is the same seat allocation as d'hondt and modified S-L.

--Dirtyrottenscoundrel (talk) 09:32, 23 October 2020 (UTC) Dirtyrottenscoundrel (talk) 09:32, 23 October 2020 (UTC)[reply]

The example was incorrect and has been corrected. Closed Limelike Curves (talk) 20:58, 2 February 2024 (UTC)[reply]

Unexplained deletion of content[edit]

@Closed Limelike Curves you are removing the Imperiali quota (post(k) = k + 2) from the divisor table (and elsewhere) without explanation in your edit comments. Please explain that here. Thank you —Quantling (talk | contribs) 20:52, 26 January 2024 (UTC)[reply]

Did I? I'll fix that; I dropped it from the table intentionally because it's:
1. Not technically a proper divisor method (signposts must be k+1) at most, and
2. Subsumed by the stationary divisor methods.
But I'll add a comment describing it as part of the stationary family of divisor methods. Closed Limelike Curves (talk) 21:00, 26 January 2024 (UTC)[reply]
  1. Yes, I've seen that you changed the text to support that "Not technically a proper divisor method (signposts must be k+1) at most", but what is your source for this restriction of at most k + 1? The restriction appears false in light of the existence of the Imperiali quota.
  2. Yes, but especially because it has a name, we should include it, yes? As in, we don't include k + π because no one uses it!
Quantling (talk | contribs) 21:06, 26 January 2024 (UTC)[reply]
Seeing no objections, I am going to restore equal footing to the Imperiali quota, including the possibility that post(k) could be greater than k + 1. —Quantling (talk | contribs) 14:48, 31 January 2024 (UTC)[reply]
The restriction is provided in Balinski and Young, as well as Pukelsheim (the two texts that form the basis for this article). fenceposts that violate the restriction k <= post(k) <= k+1 fail the exactness/idempotence axiom of proportional representation systems--a proportional representation algorithm M*(p) must be idempotent, i.e. M*(p) = M*(M*(p)). In other words, every whole number must round to itself. Closed Limelike Curves (talk) 20:58, 2 February 2024 (UTC)[reply]

Best names for the discussed methods[edit]

@Closed Limelike Curves you've renamed several of the methods discussed so that the wikilinks take us to pages that are named differently. As evidenced by the choice of the names of these linked articles, the new names appear to be inferior to the names that they have replaced. But likely you have a reason for preferring the names that you are using ... what is it? Thank you —Quantling (talk | contribs) 21:11, 26 January 2024 (UTC)[reply]

I’m not super wedded to either set of names, but my reasoning in general was that:
  1. I’d prefer to be consistent in using one set of names (American) or the other (European) throughout this article; unfortunately it’s a bit more difficult to try and make the European names fit. Adams’ method is only occasionally associated with Cambridge; the Dean and Hill methods and have no European names whatsoever.
  2. As a rule of thumb, I think it’s reasonable to go by priority (and Jefferson/Webster have priority, as they came up with the methods first).
  3. The English-language literature on this seems to lean towards using the American names more often.
Closed Limelike Curves (talk) 00:30, 27 January 2024 (UTC)[reply]

Allows zeros[edit]

@Closed Limelike Curves et al: The new column in the table "Allows zeros" might need some re-thinking. Any of the methods that gives post(k=0) = 0 can be said to not allow zeros in that every alternative will get one representative before any alternative gets a second alternative. However, if giving one representative to every alternative makes too many representatives then a floor number of votes is established and only those alternatives with that many votes will get a representative. In this case, some alternatives will get zero representatives even though "Allows zeros" is listed as "no". —Quantling (talk | contribs) 21:26, 26 January 2024 (UTC)[reply]

Seeing no objections, I am going to remove the column "Allows zeros" from the table, so that it does not mislead the reader into believing that some systems disallow zeros in all cases. —Quantling (talk | contribs) 14:50, 31 January 2024 (UTC)[reply]
@Closed Limelike Curves:. Your recent edit to restore the "Allows zeros" column to the table didn't quite work / appears incomplete. I look forward to seeing your ideas for this. Thank you —Quantling (talk | contribs) 14:31, 2 February 2024 (UTC)[reply]
Corrected, thanks. Closed Limelike Curves (talk) 20:54, 2 February 2024 (UTC)[reply]